• No results found

In this section we discuss the robustness of our results to two other bene…cial brain gain channels (uncertain migration and remittances), to the possibility of amnesties for the illegal and to a multi-country world.

31To see this note that the sign of equation 36 depends only on the term in the nu-merator (all the remaining terms are positive). The cross derivative of the nunu-merator in relation to ,handZ equals 4 .

Start with uncertain migration. In the case analyzed in this paper, when a potential migrant decides to migrate, he does so independently of his legal status, i.e.: when is pro…table to migrate, an individual has no uncertainty about his decision. Suppose, instead, that if a skilled individual does not get a legal visa, he decides with probability qS to not migrate and with probability (1 qS) to migrate regardless of the illegality condition. As expected, the skilled individuals with no legal visa that give up of migrating will contribute for a bene…cial brain gain.

However, this new formulation does not prevent the brain waste risk to arise. Therefore, since the main mechanism in this paper is not a¤ected, results are also not going to be qualitatively altered.

Consider now the case of remittances. Assume that each individual that decides to take education in the origin country receives a remit-tance Rto …nance his education32. This case is somewhat similar to the education policy above. The only di¤erence is that now who pays for the education of the young are not taxes from those that remain in the coun-try, but emigrants’ transfers. As such remittances will also contribute to increase the education incentives of individuals in the origin country.

However, remittances do not eliminate the brain waste risk that skilled individuals face under illegal migration. Therefore, again results from our central case are going to be basically the same.

Next, we look at amnesties for illegal migrants. Imagine that an individual that does not get legal status spends a share 2(0;1)of his working life in the destination country as an illegal and a share (1 ) as a legal, due to amnesties to illegal migrants33. In this case the brain waste risk will be reduced, but not totally eliminated. Therefore once more our results are not going to be changed substantially. Furthermore, politicians in recent years have been more reticent to apply amnesties for illegal migrants. If this tendency continues, the amnesty channel for reducing the brain waste risk will also become weaker34.

Finally, we discuss a multi-country world. Suppose that individuals from the origin country can migrate to i = 1;2; :::; n destination coun-tries. For simplicity we further assume that all destination countries are symmetric in every respect35. Think …rst of a scenario where all

desti-32We do not consider remittances used for other purposes besides education. This would only make a di¤erence if we also introduce credit constrained individuals.

33We can also interpret as the probability of receiving an amnesty.

34Note that the brain waste risk can also a¤ect legal migrants, especially those belonging to some ethnic groups or citizens from certain countries (Mattoo et al., 2008). As such, results in this paper could be extended to more general cases of brain waste, which do not include only illegal migrants.

35Accordingly, migrants tend to prefer countries with higher wages, with more job opportunities, and closer in terms of geographical and cultural distance.

nation countries have the same migration policy (either the open or the selective migration policy). In this case migrants will not have any pref-erence for a particular destination country. However, this can change if destination countries di¤er in the migration policy used. Accordingly, skilled workers will prefer to migrate to countries with open migration policies in order to reduce the brain waste risk. As a result, relatively to a country with a selective migration policy, a country with an open migration policy will be able to attract more skilled workers and there-fore to achieve more easily a positive self-selection36. In addition, the existence of destination countries with open migration policies can also help origin countries to achieve a bene…cial brain gain, given that as we have seen above, open migration policies increase education incentives.

7 Discussion

In this paper we have argued that since migration policies a¤ect mi-grants’ legal status, then, they also a¤ect education incentives, brain drain and self-selection. In particular, more open migration policies tend to create less illegal migration than selective migration policies, given that the latter has more restrictive criteria for admission. In this sense we have compared an open migration policy where all migrants are granted a legal visa, with a selective migration policy where migrants are selected according to skills. Accordingly, under the selective migration policy an individual that does not get a legal visa but decides to migrate becomes an illegal migrant. This is specially penalizing for skilled ille-gal migrants, because they most likely end up working as unskilled (i.e.:

brain waste). In other words, selective migration policies increase the brain waste risk that skilled workers face when migrating.

We then showed that, relatively to the open migration policy, the selective migration policy has several negative e¤ects. For the origin country it reduces the incentives of individuals to acquire education; it weakens the possibility of bene…cial brain gain to arise; and it dampens the success of education policies. For the destination country, in turn, it undermines the chances of a positive self-selection. We have also dis-cussed that these results are robust to other bene…cial brain gain chan-nels than temporary migration (uncertain migration and remittances), to amnesties for illegal migrants and to a multi-country world.

Our model then carries out some interesting policy implications for developed and developing countries. For developed countries the popu-larity of selective migration policies might be misleading. In fact, instead

36In other words, countries with more open migration policies can cancel-out the e¤ects of selective migration policies put in place in other countries.

of attracting more skilled workers, this policy might on the contrary pre-vent a positive self-selection. The rational for this result is that selective migration policies, due to the brain waste risk, can reduce the incentives of skilled workers to migrate. In turn, and now from the perspective of developing countries, education policies cannot be seen independently from the migration policies in developed countries, given that the latter a¤ect the former. Accordingly, since selective migration policies from destination countries can reduce the incentives of individuals to acquire education in the origin countries, they can also cancel out any positive e¤ects from education policies in the latter.

References

[1] Barrett, A. (1998), "The E¤ect of Immigrant Admission Criteria on Immigrant Labour Market Characteristics", Population Research and Policy Review, 17, 439-456.

[2] Bauer, T.; Lofstrom, M. and Zimmermann, K. (2000), "Immigra-tion Policy, Assimila"Immigra-tion of Immigrants, and Natives’ Sentiments towards Immigrants: Evidence from 12 OECD Countries", Swedish Economic Policy Review, 7, pp. 11-53.

[3] Beine, M.; Docquier, F. and Rapoport, H. (2001), "Brain Drain and Economic Growth: Theory and Evidence", Journal of Development Economics, 64, pp. 275-289.

[4] Beine, M.; Docquier, F. and Rapoport, H. (2008), "Brain Drain and LDC’s Growth: Winners and Losers?", The Economic Journal, 118, pp. 631-652.

[5] Bhagwati, J. and Hamada, K. (1974), "The Brain Drain, Interna-tional Integration of Markets for Professionals and Unemployment", Journal of Development Economics, 1, pp. 19-43.

[6] Bloom, D., Grenier, G. and Gunderson, M. (1995), "The Chang-ing Labour Market Position of Canadian Immigrants", Canadian Journal of Economics, 28, pp. 987-1005.

[7] Borjas, G. (1987), "Self-Selection and the Earnings of Immigrants", American Economic Review, 77, pp. 531-544.

[8] Borjas, G. J. (1993), "Immigration Policy, National Origin, and Immigrant Skills: A Comparison of Canada and the United States", in D. Card and R. Freeman (eds.), Small Di¤erences that Matter, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

[9] Chiquiar, D. and Hanson, G. (2005), "International Migration, Self-Selection, and the Distribution of Wages: Evidence from Mexico and the United States", Journal of Political Economy, 113, pp. 239-281.

[10] Chiswick, B. (1999), "Are Immigrants Favorably Self-Selected?",

American Economic Review, 89, pp. 181-185.

[11] Chiswick, B. (2001), "The Economics of Illegal Migration for the Host Economy", in M. Siddique (ed.), International Migration into the 21st Century, Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.

[12] Commander, S.; Kangasniemi, M. and Winters, L. (2004), "The Brain Drain: Curse or Boon?", in R. Baldwin and L. Winters (eds.), Challenges to Globalization, Chicago: CUP.

[13] Coniglio, N.; De Arcangelis, G. and Serlenga, L. (2006), "Intentions to Return of Undocumented Migrants: Illegality as a Cause of Skill Waste", IZA Discussion Papers 2356.

[14] Cox Edwards, A. and Ureta, M. (2003), "International Migration, Remittances and Schooling: Evidence from El Salvador", Journal of Development Economics, 72, pp. 429-461.

[15] de Brauw, A. and Giles, J. (2006), "Migrant Opportunity and the Educational Attainment of Youth in Rural China", IZA Discussion Paper 2326.

[16] Docquier, F. and Rapoport, H. (2007), "Skilled Migration: The Per-spective of Developing Countries", in J. Baghwati and G. Hanson (eds.), Skilled Migration: Prospects, Problems and Policies, Russell Sage Foundation: New York.

[17] Dos Santos, M. and Postel-Vinay, F. (2003), "Migration as a Source of Growth: The Perspective of a Developing Country", Journal of Population Economics, 16, pp. 161-176.

[18] Green, A. and Green, D. (1995), "Canadian Immigration Policy:

The E¤ectiveness of the Point System and Other Instruments", Canadian Journal of Economics, 28, pp. 1006-1041.

[19] Grubel, H. and Scott, A. (1966), "The International Flow Of Human Capital", American Economic Review, 56, pp. 268-275.

[20] Hanson, G. (2006), “Illegal Migration from Mexico to the United States”, Journal of Economic Literature, 44, pp. 869-924.

[21] Kossoudji, S. and Cobb-Clark, D. (2002), "Coming out of the Shad-ows: Learning about Legal Status and Wages from the Legalized Population", Journal of Labor Economics, 20, pp. 598-628.

[22] Mattoo, A; Neagu, I. and Õzden, Ç. (2008), "Brain Waste? Edu-cated Immigrants in the US Labor Market", Journal of Development Economics, 87, pp. 255-269.

[23] Mckenzie, D. and Rapoport, H. (2006), "Can Migration Reduce Educational Attainments? Depressing Evidence from Mexico", CReAM Discussion Paper No 601.

[24] Mckenzie, D. and Rapoport, H. (2007), "Network E¤ects and the Dynamics of Migration and Inequality: Theory and Evidence from Mexico", Journal of Development Economics, 84, pp. 1-24.

[25] Mountford, A. (1997), "Can a Brain Drain be Good for Growth in the Source Economy?", Journal of Development Economics, 53, pp.

287-314.

[26] Orrenius, P. and Zavodny, M. (2005), "Self-Selection Among Undoc-umented Immigrants from Mexico", Journal of Development Eco-nomics, 78, pp. 215-240.

[27] Passel, J. (2005), "Estimates of the Size and Characteristics of the Undocumented Population", Pew Hispanic Center Report.

[28] Rivera-Batiz, F. (1999), "Undocumented Workers in the Labor Mar-ket: An Analysis of the Earnings of Legal and Illegal Mexican Im-migrants in the United States", Journal of Population Economics, 12, pp. 91-116.

[29] Salt, J. and Stein, J. (1997), "Migration as a Business: The Case of Tra¢ cking", International Migration 35, pp. 467-494.

[30] Schultz, T. (1975), "The Value of the Ability to Deal with Disequi-libria", Journal of Economic Literature, 13, pp. 827-847.

[31] Stark, O.; Helmenstein, C. and Prskawetz, A. (1997), "A Brain Gain with Brain Drain", Economics Letters, 55, pp. 227-234.

[32] Vayrynen, R. (2003), "Illegal Immigration, Human Tra¢ cking, and Organized Crime." Discussion Paper 2003/72, World Institute for Development Economics Research.

[33] World Bank (2006), "Global Economic Prospects: Economic Impli-cations of Remittances and Migration", Washington: World Bank [34] Wright, R. and Maxim, P. (1993), "Immigration Policy and

Im-migrant Quality: Empirical Evidence from Canada", Journal of Population Economics, 6, pp. 337-352.

RELATERTE DOKUMENTER