• No results found

We proceed to evaluation of in-sample performance of different models for dividend growth. We consider all three suggested adjustments and vary s (number of years used to estimate the model for dividend growth). Also in each case we consider the model with all available data used to estimate future dividend growth (denoted by s=*). All predictive regressions estimated with OLS in EViews. The results are summarized in Exhibit 1. It should be noted that t-statistics were computed with OLS standard errors without any adjustments.

However, it was reasonable, because neither heteroscedasticity nor autocorrelation was detected in fitted residuals in all regressions at the conventional significance levels (1%, 5%, 10%). The results for AR(1) and ARMA(1,1) models of dividend growth are presented only for s=*, because when we use rolling window approach, values and t-statistics are essentially zero (even when s=30).

Moreover, there is no evidence so far to use AR and ARMA models with time-varying coefficients and such poor performance confirms that we simply create noise when allow for time-varying.

At first glance, we can conclude three things. First of all, we see that and exhibit weak performance when we start the sample from 1937, but fit changes drastically if we shift starting point of predictive regressions to 1947. It is related to the fact that 10-20 observations are very low numbers to deliver stable estimates of AR and ARMA models. Therefore, between 1937 and 1947 both and show enormous variation, but then they stabilize. In turn, stabilizes much faster and performs good even in the long subsample.

Second, if we ignore the exception above, all three models clearly outperform simple predictive regression with regular log price-dividend ratio. Therefore, we confirm results of Lacerda and Santa-Clara (2010) and Koijen and van Binsbergen (2010). Finally, there is no model, which is obviously more parsimonious than others. Still it is worth mentioning that for s=* all three models almost replicate each other when we consider the short subsamples (from 1947).

Page 12

suggested models; however, detailed out-of-sample performance evaluation is required to make further conclusions.

Page 13

Ang, A., and J. Liu, 2004. How to discount cashflows with time-varying expected returns. Journal of Finance, 59: 2745–2783.

Ball, Ray, 1978. Anomalies in relationships between securities' yields and yield-surrogates. Journal of Financial Economics, 6: 103-126.

Bekaert, G., E. Engstrom, and S. R. Grenadier, 2001. Stock and bond pricing in an affine economy. NBER Working Paper No. 7346.

Brennan, M. J., and Y. Xia, 2005. Persistence, predictability, and portfolio planning. Working Paper, UCLA.

Burnside, C., 1998. Solving asset pricing models with gaussian shocks. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 22: 329–340.

Campbell, John Y. and Robert Shiller, 1987. The dividend-price ratio and expectations of future dividends and discount factors. Unpublished manuscript (Princeton University, Princeton, NJ).

Campbell, John Y. and Robert Shiller, 1988. The dividend-price ratio and expectations of future dividends and discount factors. Review of Financial Studies, 1:195–227.

Cochrane, J. H.,2007. The dog that did not bark: A defense of return predictability. Review of Financial Studies, 21 (4):1533–1575.

Cochrane, J. H.,2008. State-space vs. VAR models for stock returns. Working paper. University of Chicago.

Dow, Charles H., 1920. Scientific stock speculation. The Magazine of Wall Street (New York).

Fama, E. and Kenneth French, 1988. Dividend yields and expected stock returns.

Journal of Financial Economics, 22:3–27.

Flood, Robert P., Robert J. Hodrick, and Paul Kaplan, 1986. An evaluation of recent evidence on stock market bubbles. Unpublished manuscript (National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA).

Goetzmann W. N., and P. Jorion, 1995. A longer look at dividend yields. Journal of Business, 68: 483-508.

Gordon, Myron J., (1959). Dividends, earnings and stock prices. Review of Economics and Statistics (The MIT Press), 41 (2): 99-105.

Goyal, A., and I. Welch, 2008. A comprehensive look at the empirical performance of equity premium prediction. Review of Financial Studies, 21:

1455-1508.

Koijen R., and J. van Binsbergen, 2010. Predictive regressions: A present-value approach. Journal of Finance, 65 (4).

Lacerda, F., and P. Santa-Clara, 2010. Forecasting dividend growth to better predict returns. Working Paper. Available at http://docentes.fe.unl.pt/~psc

Lettau, M., and S. van Nieuwerburgh, 2008. Reconciling the return predictability evidence. Review of Financial Studies, 21 (4):1607–1652.

Page 14 Journal of Political Economy, 112(1):1–47.

Pastor, L., and P. Veronesi, 2003. Stock valuation and learning about profitability.

Journal of Finance, 58: 1749–1789.

Pastor, L., and P. Veronesi, 2006. Was There a Nasdaq Bubble in the Late 1990s?

Journal of Financial Economics, 81: 61–100.

Pastor, L., and R. F. Stambaugh, 2006. Predictive systems: living with imperfect predictors. Working Paper, University of Chicago and CRSP.

Rozeff, Michael, 1984. Stock prices and social dynamics. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2: 457-498.

Rytchkov, O., 2007. Filtering out expected dividends and expected returns.

Unpublished paper, Texas A&M.

Trojani, F., and Piatti I., 2012. Dividend growth predictability and the price-dividend ratio. Swiss finance institute research paper, 12-42. Available at SSRN:

http://ssrn.com/abstract=2077381

Page 15

This table summarizes the results of estimation of different predictive regressions.

Each regression includes next period log return as a dependent variable, while four different subsamples are considered for each predictor (2007, 1937-2012, 1947- 2007 and 1947-2012). The detailed description of different adjustments for price-dividend ratio is presented in Section 2. "s" denotes a number of previous observations used for estimation of next period log dividend growth. "s=*" corresponds to the case when all available by the current moment observations are used for estimation of next period log dividend growth. For each predictive regression three values are presented: , slope and t-statistic. "*" inside the t-statistic's field reflects the significance at the 5%-level, while "**" denotes the significance at the 1%-level. The best predictor in terms of either or t-statistic is highlighted for each subsample (bold font).

Predictor s 1937-2007 1937-2012

Slope t-stat Slope t-stat

10 14.29% -0.0785 -3.3913** 11.94% -0.0775 -3.1682**

20 - - - - - -

* 7.60% -0.1102 -2.3821* 7.29% -0.1169 -2.4121*

* 1.70% -0.0408 -1.0929 1.77% -0.0454 -1.1546 * 0.38% 0.0126 0.5118 0.38% 0.0139 0.535

4.98% -0.0768 -1.9009 6.73% -0.0932 -2.3116*

Predictor s 1947-2007 1947-2012

Slope t-stat Slope t-stat

10 16.18% -0.0871 -3.3751** 13.27% -0.0865 -3.1290**

20 15.07% -0.1283 -3.2355** 12.20% -0.1237 -2.9819**

* 17.32% -0.1721 -3.5159** 15.78% -0.182 -3.4624**

* 16.88% -0.1673 -3.4610** 15.26% -0.1763 -3.3950**

* 17.50% -0.161 -3.5373** 12.73% -0.1514 -3.0556**

9.05% -0.0986 -2.4235* 10.90% -0.1165 -2.7981**