• No results found

EFFECTS OF THE COMPOSITION OF INCOME ON THE OPTIMUM TAX DESIGN It would be interesting to know how changes ~n the composition of

where a partial derivative is indicated by subscript a

5. EFFECTS OF THE COMPOSITION OF INCOME ON THE OPTIMUM TAX DESIGN It would be interesting to know how changes ~n the composition of

income would affect the optimum tax policy. For instance would a larger exogenous component work in favour of higher or lower progres-sivity? More precisely we may ask: If the population with the original characteristics were replaced by a population with the same observed distribution of actual income but with higher exogenous income and lower earned income, would the government then want to change the tax policy. This is obviously a complicated question.

If we consider the first order condition for the optimum tax rate, there are a number of effects to take into account. In general little or nothing can be said about how substitution effects, in-come effects, etc. change with the wage rate, exogenous income, etc.

It may, however, be of interest to consider simple cases.

Let us first make clear some implications of the experiment we conceive of. First, there is no change in I. for i

=

1, ••• ,n at the

~

original tax policy. It follows that C. is also left unchanged for

~

all i. Moreover, the tax revenue constraint remains fulfilled without changing any tax parameters. However, it may be desirable to change the tax policy.

13

-Let us consider the case where the preferences of the individuals are represented by a Stone-Geary utility function:

(33) u

=

a ln(L - L) + ln(C -

C)

where L denotes leisure, a is a positive parameter and

L

and C are parameters usually interpreted as minimum requirements.

Let us define

(34) x

=

L - L

and

(35)

y

= C - C

The budget constraint can then be expressed as (36) m

=

w* + (1 - t)e + a -

C -

w*£

=

w*x + y

where the available amount of time (for labour and leisure) has been set equal to unity.

The Gossen condition becomes

*

=

w

which is equivalent to

*

w x == ay or

1

*

y=-wx.

a

Also employing the budget constraint,we then get the demand functions:

(38)

m C C,

Y

=

+ a =

-ma

-x = = L

-

L

=

1

-

h

-

L .

( 1 + a)w*

(37)

- 14

-We see that

(39)

ah

w-

aa =

- (1 + a)(l - t)

which is independent of wand e.

The Slutsky derivatives with respect to the net wage rate, s xw and s ,are derived from the Gossen condition and the condition that

yw

Since our experiment leaves e and y unchanged, w2 shw also retains its initial value.

Inspecting (9) we now see that if preferences are of the Stone-Geary type, there will be no change in

(I-

aI). The absolute value of

X

can of course be manipulated by the conventional choice of units of welfare. It is convenient to keep

X

fixed. Then there will be no

change in the second and third term of (10), i.e. the efficiency terms.

- 15

-The remaining question is how the first term, i.e. the equity term, is affected. When ~ is fixed, the change in the covariance equals redA. - O)I./n=cov(dA., 1.). If the changes in the marginal welfare

1. 1. 1. 1.

weights are negatively correlated with income, the marginal tax rate should be increased. Let us assume that initially marginal welfare weights are negatively correlated with income. Then the covariance will be reduced if marginal welfare weights are reduced relatively more at higher income levels than they are at lower income levels neglecting the requirement that the mean value should be preserved.2)

Since the mean restoring adjustments are proportional changes,

absolute mean preserving changes in the marginal welfare weights will then be negatively correlated with income. The relative change in some marginal welfare weight, A, when e increases and w changes to keep income unaltered, is from

(22)

and

(24):

(42)

A lA -

a

heIse

a a w

(1 - t)de.

1 +

heIse

a w

Unfortunately there is not much to say about how this expression changes with income in general. However, it may be interesting

to consider the special case in which distributional preferences are adequately represented by the special cardinalisation of the utility function presented in formula (33). Let us first introduce the corresponding indirect utility function, denoted, by v, which is obtained by plugging (37) and (38) into (33):

(43) a In ( ma ) + In m

where

...

a is defined implicitly.

- 16

-We easily derive that (44)

x =

1+am

= --

y1

(45)

x

a

=

1+a

m2

and hence

(46)

x

a

-,,-

= --- m

I would like to argue that this is not an arbitrary special case, but rather one which may have a special claim for interest. In applied welfare economics the welfare weight is frequently assumed to be some

isoelastie function of total consumption expenditure

(47)

-o

Jo.

=

C

(See for example Stem (1977».

As a special case o is often assumed to be unity, which may even have some empirical support. (See Christiansen and Jansen (1978, p. 233). If in addition the minimum consumption requirement, C,

is zero, (44) and (47) are equal. Even if

C

> 0, one can hardly argue that (44) is a less plausible specification than (46).

We find from (39) and '(41) that

a ha (1+a)w

*

--=

Sew

aI =

--

y

(1+Ct)w

*

and from(39):

- 17

-*

Cl

Ca

= w

ha + 1

=

1 - --~--

=

---l+a 1+0.

Hence

ha 1

Ca Sew

= -

~(-:-l+-Cl~)-y-

= -

-m-due to (37).

The numerator of the fraction in (42) then becomes

A-lA - h C Is =

a a a ew m

The denomimator becomes

l-L w

*

--- =

(l-L)w

_. *

(1+a) y

We see that if the utility function (33)

represents

the individual preferences as ~ell as the distributional preferences of the government,

then the optimum degree of income tax progressivity

is

unaffected by the composition of income.

Intuitively it might be tempting to believe that the existence of exogenous income should lead to a higher marginal tax rate because efficiency effects might be believed to be less important and perhaps because high income people might be believed to have more unearned

income. But in general this intuition does not hold. As we have seen the composition of income is not necessarily important. But in general we cannot tell whether studies of optimum taxation neglecting exogenous

income tend to over - or underestimate the optimum marginal tax rate.

18

-FOOTNOTES

1) Let E(w*,V) denote the expenditure function. From the condition

*

-l

E(w ,V(w*,(l-t)e+a»

=

(l-t)e+a we find that A equals E • Hence

v

= - E-2 E

v w*v

= E -h E

-?

v a v

=

Aha

2) As an alternative formulation we could divide (10) by ~ and consider the covariance

r.

(A.I~ - l)1.In. The change would then be

1. 1.

cov(d(A.

I~),

1.) •

1. 1.

3) These effects are analyzed lonmore detail in Christiansen (1983).

4) A more straightforward route is to observe that S1.nce A

=

u

c'

which only depends on C, A does not change when C remains the same.

19 -REFERENCES

Christiansen, V. and E.S. Jansen, 1978, Implicit social preferences in the Norwegian system of indirect taxation, Journal of Public Economics 10, 217-245.

Christiansen, V., 1983, Some important properties of the social marginal utility of income, Scandinavian Journal of Economics 85, 359-371.

Sandmo, A. and A. Dixit, 1977, Some simplified formulae for optimal in-come taxation, Scandinavian Journal of Economics 79, 417-423.

Stern, N. H., 1977, Welfare weights and the elasticity of the marginal valuation of income, in: M.J. Artis and A.R. Nobay, eds., Studies in modern economic analysis: The proceedings of the AUTE conference in Edinburgh 1976 (Blackwell, Oxford).

VC/SH

5

INCOME TAXATION OF TWO-PERSON HOUSEHOLDS